What makes good deflation so desirable? It all starts when increased output is possible with fewer resources overall. Once price reductions per unit come into play, they in turn lead to real wage gains and higher productivity levels. I believe that good deflation could become a services sector response to counteract high inflation and rising interest rates. Given the many positives of good deflation, what accounts for such resistance to its potential in housing and time based services?
Even though both areas must deal with the natural scarcities of time and place, much of the bias against good deflation potential is inadvertent and political in nature. Not only are such biases protectionist, they discourage adaptive evolution in time and place based product - evolution which could otherwise augment their capacity despite their natural limitations. While time based skill and land as real estate are certainly not exponential in nature, they could still add additional output through flexible coordination of knowledge and land use potential.
Bias characteristics also differ depending on the markets and sectors in question. For instance, progressives and conservatives increasingly prefer a restoration of local manufacturing over global free trade. Fortunately - even though this anti free market bias will increase manufacturing costs to some degree - globalized manufacture should continue benefiting nations in the foreseeable future. At the very least, it's reasonable to expect good deflation to ultimately be restored in global markets. Once tradable sector resource access is more stable and predictable, it should become more cost effective as well.
Societies are fortunate indeed, that tradable sector activity is often managed for full production efficiencies. Still, during times of high inflation, we're reminded of the dangers of taking good deflation in tradable sectors for granted. Indeed, relying on the serendipity of long term good deflation (along with the more recent low inflation pattern) made it easy to disregard the long term inefficiencies of non tradable sectors. These inefficiencies remain in place due to countless quality requirements, many of which have been exacerbated by government subsidies.
Recall however, that these requirements end up as ever more inputs in relation to aggregate output. Even when quality gains are worth additional costs for some, other groups suffer efficiency losses which in turn require additional personal labour for non discretionary needs. Consequently when it comes to quality of life, some income groups are actually moving backwards. Again, constant calls for higher wages occur because lower income groups need to work more hours than is sometimes feasible to meet their financial responsibilities.
Fortunately there are already better production methods which could establish disinflation in housing - methods which could eventually lead to good deflation as well. Just the same, a considerable amount of social and political bias has prevented the majority of flexible housing options. In this restrictive environment, progressives tend to focus on time based constraints for meeting financial obligations. Whereas conservatives are more concerned about place based constraints, such as immigrants who are seen as competing for already scarce housing.
Despite the protectionism that stands in the way of production reform, housing is still a simpler issue to solve than markets based on time and personal skill. Hence countering excess monetary demand could begin with more flexible interpretations of housing for all income levels. Otherwise, many individuals will remain subject to the first mover problem of providing valuable services for others by more accessible means, only to be locked out of the housing necessary for this to happen. For that matter, one of the main reasons wages recently increased for the lowest income levels, is that employers were faced with the fact no housing existed nearby which their employees could afford.
Societies need to focus on non tradable sector production issues, since they are at the heart of recent inflation which is proving difficult to eradicate. However, there's something else important about productivity expectations which needs to be noted here. When productivity involves final product which is independent of personal labour, these areas do have capacity for exponential output. Since our economic time is not exponential, it often demands a higher price as a fixed quantity. In these instances, people rely on investments in knowledge and skill to increase their time value. Alas, institutions then tend to respond by substituting away from time based input, in order to meet their financial obligations! Despite the obvious drawbacks of this effect, our current understanding of productivity gains makes it a rational approach, especially if institutional budgets are already in jeopardy.
How, then, could good deflation be achieved in skills use without having to substitute away from time based input? One way is to make mutual time commitments, or time arbitrage, a valid and measurable economic unit. Skill sets would be voluntarily chosen and independent of monetary value. However, group effort would also utilize monetary compensation as a base to keep the process in motion. Time arbitrage might help societies maintain and preserve what they build and create, plus the knowledge and skills involved would be simultaneously measured as cumulative gains. Time as an economic unit of value is also one way to overcome the Baumol effect and ultimately, achieve good deflation in time based services. Again, production gains would transpire on completely different terms in these settings. Once housing production reform begins in earnest, economic validity for mutual time commitments would be the logical next step.