Regular readers have probably noticed I've not had much time for blogging recently. However it's mostly due to a good reason: I'm in the process of finalizing material, for the first book of a series which will also eventually become part of the blog sidebar. This past August, I'd begun settling into a schedule of wrapping up chapter material each month, before continuing to the next chapter. Of course as it turned out, the third chapter ran three weeks longer than expected - given my self imposed deadline! Hopefully that won't happen too often, so I'll still have time for blogging, and particularly so the initial part of this extended writing project will be complete (finally!) by summer's end of 2019.
There'll be eight chapters in the first book and they should be ready for their last edit (prior to this initial publication) by late spring. Once Time as Wealth is complete, I'll be able to set my sights on some pressing macroeconomic concerns which are the main focus for the second book. Afterward, the third book will describe a potential institution which - alongside for profit endeavour (physical building and infrastructure components) - would support a time/generational continuum for mutual employment and knowledge preservation. In particular, an institutional structure is needed which can address the widespread structural dilemma which is also a result of the Baumol effect. Meanwhile, here's a few highlights from Time as Wealth.
1) The Untapped Potential of Time Value
Many discussions re time as wealth, understandably focus on the reality of personal time scarcities in relation to institutions which already exist. But what if it were possible to position our economic time value within a context of institutional adaptation? Importantly, a marketplace for time value, would mean greater monetary equivalence for all time use potential. This approach would help compensate for the fact nominal wages may be slow to adjust upward, during historical periods of service sector dominance. Indeed: The tradable sector dominance of our recent past, was likely a greater contributor to relative income equality than is generally recognized. That relative loss in tradable sector output - hence relative wage loss - is a recipe for political fragility. Gains in aggregate time value could help restore a rising standard of living, and bring a new dimension to productivity as well.
2) Imagine and Create the Markets We Want
How might a well defined marketplace for time value, actually benefit society? For one, there is a growing zero sum mentality in the political arena, which has been exacerbated by the exclusivity and polarization of today's non tradable sectors. By taking all time use potential into account, more inclusive and less polarized workplaces would eventually take shape. What makes greater inclusion feasible, is that mutual reciprocity creates wealth at the outset, instead of having to demand resource capacity from elsewhere. Reciprocal wealth building, means new economic options that go well beyond the skills exclusivity of many present day workplaces.
3) From Skills Arbitrage to Time Arbitrage
Is it possible to differentiate how we value the overall use of our time, from how we came to define the value of skills investments in 20th century workplaces? All too often, the commitments of our skills priorities have meant giving short shrift to other time priorities and responsibilities. In some respects, time arbitrage could prove a more flexible means of services coordination, than skills arbitrage. Time arbitrage could tap the use of knowledge in non rival ways which help to preserve the spread of knowledge throughout society. Not only could time arbitrage restore our capacity to manage the time necessary for personal commitments, it could allow local groups to coordinate a broader range of skill sets than is presently possible.
4) Autonomy, Personal Agency and Economic Freedom
Governments and private industry alike, have long been complicit in mutual agreements which reduce our economic freedoms. How can a society expect to preserve political freedom, without economic freedom? Nevertheless, the freedom to produce is not as prominent among supporters of free markets as one might expect. Much of the usurpation of knowledge production rights in particular, took place well before wealth came to be strongly associated with knowledge. Indeed, the dialogue of victimization likely emerged in part due to a lack of understanding, how production rights have slowly but surely been lost. Production rights are an important part of our potential happiness and satisfaction in life, in that they make autonomy and personal agency a viable option for society as a whole.
5) From Divisions of Labour to Mutual Time Priorities
Not only do we need to closely examine future possibilities for time management, we also need to take a broader perspective regarding the rationality of mutually held time commitments. While tradable sector activity continued to dominate, time management was often a secondary concern, given the obvious demands of these kinds of organizational activity. However, non tradable sector organization has not been near as efficient, or as complete in terms of production potential. Possibly the best way to think about regaining efficiency for time based services product, is to envision the process as one of mutual employment for mutually held time priorities.
6) A Place in the Sun for Students of Life
How did our personal enjoyment of experiential and practical knowledge, become so lost in the demands of formal education? If that weren't enough: Formalized education has made it exceedingly difficult for average citizens without college degrees, to participate in some of the most important issues of our times. It is said we need to vote if we want a good societal outcome. Nevertheless, there's little in the political area which actually addresses the most pressing issues of the day. And many vital issues - instead of being worked out at a societal level - are inexplicably "roped off" for educational papers and high level discussions. Let's create more meaningful roles which include economic context, for students of life with an avid interest in lifelong learning, yet little means by which to share that passion in productive ways with others.
7) Building a Continuum for Knowledge Preservation
Even though generational wisdom may appear irrelevant or outdated, there is hidden fragility in the systems of our times. Knowledge tends to utilized in ways which don't necessarily carry a reliable continuum or momentum. Important information may actually be lost at times, in part due to how its use is organizationally structured. How might societies reduce this risk? An important aspect of this conundrum, is a wall of separation between schools and workplaces which prevent students from taking active roles in the economic and civic lives of their communities. Even though social and economic mobility will always be important, more communities need the economic option of being able to play direct roles in the knowledge preservation and utilization processes they have supported for so long, via formal education.
8) An Overview for a New Institutional Role
A new institution is needed, which can productively respond to the fact that time value scales differently from other forms of value. Time based product is vitally important in multiple aspects of our lives, especially since it contains an experiential nature which cannot be replicated in any other way. Nevertheless, the only way to make time based product truly efficient, is to provide an economic dimension in which time can directly function in relation to itself. Knowledge and human value would be able to scale up in this arrangement, so as to compensate for the fact this system wouldn't directly capture full monetary representation. Participants would generate the monetary equivalence of real wage value, through their creation of service options which otherwise would not be possible.
There's another important aspect of monetary equivalence in this arrangement. Each participant would build lifetime ownership in both local building components and physical infrastructure, and have ownership options as well in the manufacture of these components which are sold globally. This active citizen shareholding position, would make it possible for central banks to indirectly represent the labour of these groups (which otherwise couldn't function as a liquid asset), via their share of ownership in the for profit role of the equilibrium corporation.
No comments:
Post a Comment